By Robin Johnson1
Recent analyses of private investment in Research and Development in NZ, such as that of Weshah Razzak and Julia Hall, have utilised some rough data approximations for the period from 1960 to 1990 before the MoRST survey came into effect. On the public investment side, there are more adequate records of government departmental expenditures and grants going back to the 1960s. This paper reports on a suggestion (made originally by Ralph Lattimore) that the expenditure on Research and Development by para-statals like the marketing boards would offer some guidance. The relevance of this is that the MoRST survey classifies marketing boards as part of the private sector and not the public sector. Business investment cannot be retrieved retrospectively, unfortunately. The boards supported a series of research institutes (like DRI, MIRINZ, and WRONZ) who were ostensibly part of the processing sector but which also did R & D for primary producers. These institutes also received government grants through the DSIR. In the event, only 3 institutes - WRONZ, DRI and LASRA(2) - could provide records of research expenditure back to 1960. Hence the title of this paper - the proposal is that the combined expenditure of three of the institutes could provide a proxy for not only all the other institutes but also that of the business sector! This series was then adjusted to the 1989 determinations of MoRST to create a new series of private investment in NZ Research and Development. This paper discusses these techniques and compares the resulting data with earlier results determined by the author (Johnson 1999).
There have been several recent studies of the role of Research and Development investment in the economy (Johnson 1999, Johnson 2000a, Johnson, Razzak and Stillman 2006, Hall and Scobie 2006). These studies are dependent on the research data available on business and government expenditure on Research and Development. Hall and Scobie employ original estimates for the agricultural sector back to 1927. Private investment is proxied by utilising an indicator of government (DSIR) grants to the sector. Since 1989, MoRST (and latterly Statistics New Zealand) have conducted a bi-annual survey of firms and organisations to determine annual spending in the private sector, in the government sector, and in the universities. Before 1989 there are fairly good records on government expenditure but very little on the business sector and the universities.
The data sets used by the various authors are dependent on the MoRST (1999 and others) survey and government records available before 1989. For Johnson and Razzak studies, a series of private sector estimates determined by Johnson (1999) are employed. For the universities this involved taking a varying proportion of the annual grant to the universities from government for the years before 1989 and interpolating this data with the MoRST data. For the private sector, the ratio of 1989 private expenditure to GDP was extrapolated back to 1960 in line with government expenditure (Table A1 below). The business sector was renamed the private sector, and government and the universities were combined to define the public sector. Hall and Scobie build on the Scobie and Eveleens' paper (1986), and derive agricultural private Research and Development expenditure from the DSIR grants to the research associations.
My hypothesis is that the private investment record before 1990 would be more acceptable if it were derived from original data of some sort than derived from some varying proportion of GDP. Talking to Ralph Lattimore in August 2005 I realised that some records could survive from the industry research associations which make up an important proportion of the MoRST definition of 'business' R & D. (For some reason, MoRST classified the industry research associations as 'business' and the CRIs as 'government' while Government heavily subsidised them both). To this end, I contacted six of the remaining industry institutes for their records of research expenditure but was only able to locate records for three - DRI, Leather and WRONZ. The remaining three were MIRINZ, Cawthron and the Fertiliser Association. As a fallback from this line of enquiry I re-investigate the kinds of grants and subsidies available for private sector Research and Development in the 1960s, 1970s and 1980s.In this paper, I set out the new estimates of private Research and Development expenditure, their relation to what I prepared in 1999 (Tables A2, A3, and A4), and some new estimates of the research stock elasticities with respect to total factor productivity (TFP), followed by a section of the research grants given to private entities. The results for the research associations are generally disappointing but they do suggest further interpretations of the R & D history of NZ are possible and future workers could build on them. The results for the analysis based on government grants are more promising and suggest further areas of work.
With the cooperation of the research associations, I collected the annual Research and Development current expenditure in financial years in current dollars for the three organisations for the period 1962-1990. This is what they actually spent and does not include capital expenditure. Some of it would have been funded by government subsidy especially in the 1960s and 1970s. I then estimated a national total of private expenditure on the assumption that each year's national figure was proportional to that of the three institutes and joining the MoRST figure for 1989-90 (Table A4). The results show that expenditure was somewhat lower in the 1960s and 1970s with a period of rapid catch up in the 1980s as compared with the previous estimate.(3) I then computed a new set of stocks of private knowledge and combined these with the existing estimates of public stocks. The stock transformation is shown at the foot of Table A3.
In Johnson (1999) these estimates of Research and Development stocks were tested in a TFP framework on the assumption that the effects of previous Research and Development expenditure would be brought out in the Solow residual rather than directly on industry net output. In addition, foreign spillovers were incorporated in the form of Australian R & D expenditure and government education expenditure in NZ and these were explored as a measure of human skills and other factors outside the Research and Development effects on Solow productivity. The TFP measure was derived from the Philpott data set and capital and labour were weighted by fixed weights based the average shares of income for the period concerned. The estimation equation looked like this:
(1) TFPit = Const +B1PVTR & DSit-1 + B2PUBResearch and DevelopmentS it-1 + B3AUSResearch and DevelopmentSt-1 +B4EDUt-1
where the i's refer to industry categories in the old NZSIC SNA system and S shows that the stock of research knowledge is being tested. Education expenditure does not enter as a stock.
Due to the incompleteness of the Yearbook records of Government expenditure on Research and Development before 1990, Philpott's 21 industry categories were summarised into 9 categories: Agriculture, Fishing , Forestry, Primary Processing, Manufacturing, Building and Construction, Transport and Storage, Energy and Services. The aggregate data was for the Market Economy (MK) that is, TFP was estimated for all the then NZSIC categories excluding Ownership of Dwellings and the Government sector.
In the case of industry equations in the form of (1), separate categories of Research and Development stocks were identified previously and tested (see Table A5). As this methodology was also very approximate, we now test some alternatives to this procedure as well. We use the agriculture sector as an example in this paper.
There is a fairly complete record, compiled by NRAC, of the grants paid out by government departments to various entities for R & D activities. I assume that this was largely paid to the private sector though cross-departmental grants cannot be ruled out. I propose to re-examine this data, available from 1964-65 fiscal year to 1985-86. From 1985-86 to 1989-90 I extrapolated this series in proportion to DSIR grants (Table A6).
Table 1 shows the results for the re-estimation of equation (1) for the market sector as defined by Philpott (1994). The tabulation shows the successive estimates made as the data was assembled and refined up to the present time. The results given in the 1999 conference paper were modified in the same year as a mistake was made in the lag system and were published in Johnson (2000b). Successive re-estimations show the effect of:
(a) the new data for private expenditure from
the research association for the same period as previously,
(b) the effect of extending the 1999 Research and Development data up to
2002,
(c) the effect of extending the new data for private expenditure up
to 2002, and
(d) the effect of using the government grant series.
The broad pattern emerges that accumulated stocks of private R & D knowledge are consistently related to the following year's Solow residual. The accumulated stocks of public Research and Development are negatively related to the following year's TFP. There are reasonably consistent relationships between TFP and Australian R & D stocks, but somewhat negative relationships with the level of vote education. This may be because EDU is a poor indicator of skill levels or changes in the Solow residual are driven from elsewhere.
Table 1: Experiments with the Market Economy TFP | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Elasticities | ||||||
Description | Constant | PVT | PUB | AUS | EDU | R2 |
1. Conference 1999 1962-98 |
-1.12 | 0.34* | -0.35* | 0.15** | 0.04 | 0.95 |
2. 1999 Revision 1962-98 |
-0.95 | 0.39* | -0.38* | 0.13* | 0.02 | 0.95 |
3. Res Assns Revision 1962-98 |
6.17 | 0.10 | -0.07 | 0.25** | -0.21* | 0.89 |
4. No 2 to 2002 |
0.96 | 0.75** | -0.67** | 0.04 | 0.03 | 0.95 |
5. No 3 to 2002 | 7.72 | 0.25* | -0.12* | 0.11** | -0.32** | 0.87 |
6. Cobb Douglas model1 1962-98 |
-0.93 | 0.57** | -0.59** | 0.07 | 0.03 | 0.99 |
7. Grants model 1965-90 1965-02 |
-1.50 | 0.56** | -0.40** | 0.23** | -0.20* | 0.88 |
** Significant at 1 per cent level | ||||||
* Significant at 5 per cent level | ||||||
(1) This equation took the form Output=F(L,K,PVTS,PUBS,AUSS,EDU) |
The new data from the research associations contributes nothing in the period 1962-98 but resurfaces over the longer period 1962-2002. In the period 1962-98, public stocks of Research and Development are now non-sgnificant but also re-emerge in 1962-02. The Cobb Douglas model confirms the earlier results for 1962-98 for private and public stocks of Research and Development knowledge. The rates of return on depreciated capital invested in private and public Research and Development vary from $11.9 to $17 per $ invested in the private case and $-4.8 to $-7 in the public case (Johnson 2000b, pp.10-19). The grants model (7) is an improvement on result (5) when the RA ivestment variable is replaced by a grant variable (Table A6). In this specification there is also a significant association with Australian Research and Development investment and a negative relationship to Education spending. For the period 1965-98 the grants model also works well.as compared with (3)
The new data on private investment in Research and Development by RAs is disappointing. The private investment series based on proportions of national income used from 1999 onwards was possibly picking up systematic fluctuations in national income. This then became reflected in the stock of Research and Development in a given year. Since the dependent variable, TFP, was set as a function of that stock in the previous year, a very positive relationship emerged. The actual expenditure by the research associations appears to be independent of changes in GDP. It is possible that government grants change as Budget policy changes which could be associated with changes in GDP.
The next section is devoted to the way I treated individual sectors of the economy in the 1999 analysis. The Johnson et al (2006) paper and the Hall and Scobie paper also used the same data base. It will be recalled that historic data availabilities restricted the analyis to 9 sectors, viz, Agriculture, Fishing, Forestry, Primary Processing, Manufacturing, Energy, Building, Transport, and Services. For the Research and Development data set, categories were matched by groupings of 'output areas' according to the then MoRST definitions. In the case of private investment in Research and Development the MoRST data only ran from the 1989-90 fiscal year. For the period 1962-90 the sector shares were based on the MoRST 1990 survey (Table A5). (In addition, after the publication of the 1999 results, the sector shares were revised to take in the university shares).
The analysis will proceed in steps in the following order:
(a) the effect of the revised 1999 share
allocation 1962-98
(b) the effect of the new definition of PVT 1962-98
(c) the effect of updating the data series to 2002
(d) the effect of spillovers in Research and Development, and,
(e) the effect of the grants variable.
The question of spillovers arises because each industry sector obtains new knowledge from the total body of previous research carried out. It may be that in a statistical snse that a given industry group may show a greater sympathy with national trends than with its own sector trends. In addition, the concept of `own? research for an industry is very hazy and in the MoRST surveys is nominated by the providers. There is more discussion of this problem in the Summary and Conclusions section.
Table 2 shows the effects on the agriculture sector of the revised share allocations between industries shown in Table A5. The 1999 estimation gave a very strong indication of positive relationships. The 1999 revision likewise. When the university shares were introduced, the elasticities were smaller for PVT and PUB but stayed the same sign and significance.
Table 2: Experiments with the Agriculture Sector TFP (1) 1962-98 | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Change of Shares | ||||||
Description | Constant | PVT | PUB | AUST | EDU | R2 |
1. Conference 1999 | 3.31 | 2.59** | -2.32** | -0.43* | 0.77** | 0.96 |
2. 1999 Revision | 4.87 | 2.91** | -2.51** | -0.46* | 0.60* | 0.96 |
3. 2003 share revision | 5.50 | 2.40** | -2.02** | -0.71* | 0.76* | 0.95 |
Table 3 shows the effect of introducing the RA definition of private stocks. Three things have happened: the new PVT stock has no statistical relationship to agricultural TFP; it also drags the public stock variable out of the analysis, and Australian Research and Development stocks appear to have a considerable effect on agricultural TFP.
Table 3: Experiments with the Agriculture Sector TFP (2) 1962-98 | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Change of PVT definition | ||||||
Description | Constant | PVT | PUB | AUST | EDU | R2 |
1. Research Associations Revision old shares | -4.69 | -0.07 | 0.06 | 0.73* | -0.22 | 0.86 |
2. Research Associations + new shares | -4.87 | -0.08 | 0.06 | 0.76* | -0.23 | 0.86 |
Table 4 shows the effect of enlarging the sample to 1962-2002. Public stocks appear to drop out in the longer period but re-appear when the university shares are included. The new private stocks remain non-significant as before and Australain Research and Development stocks re-appear as they had previously.
Table 4: Experiments with the Agriculture Sector TFP (3) 1962-02 | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Change of period | ||||||
Description | Constant | PVT | PUB | AUST | EDU | R2 |
1. 1999 shares 62-02 | -0.52 | 0.56** | -0.29 | 0.05 | 0.05 | 0.90 |
2. Revised shares 62-02 | 3.10 | 0.92** | -0.48** | -0.48 | 0.25 | 0.91 |
3. RA's+old shares 62-02 | -3.61 | 0.10 | 0.11 | 0.49** | -0.16 | 0.88 |
4. RA's+03 shares 62-02 | -0.81 | 0.22 | 0.05 | 0.28 | -0.29 | 0.88 |
Table 5 shows some results testing the spillover hypothesis. In 1. we test whether national PVT Research and Development stocks would offer a better explanation of changes in agriculture TFP in place of the supposed agriculture share. The elasticity is greater than earlier results but at a lesser degree of significance. Public stocks in agriculture are non-significant and Australian stocks take their place. In 2. we test whether national public investment is more important than agricultural public investment alongside the research association definition of private agricultural investment. Apparently nothing works in this specification. In 3. we test whether we can replace both private and public agricultural stocks with the respective national stocks. As might perhaps be expected there is no significant association and Australian stocks appear to be dominant.
Table 6 shows the results when the 'Grants' definition of private investment is substituted in the estimation. The 'Grants' set only starts in 1964-65. No 1. shows that the agricultural share of the grants variable is non-significant as are the other independent variables in the period 1965-98. No 2. shows that this result is confirmed
Table 5: Experiments with the Agriculture Sector TFP (4) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Spillovers | ||||||
Description | Constant | PVT | PUB | AUST | EDU | R2 |
1. Total PVT 1962-02 | -0.53 | 0.53 | -0.22 | 0.42** | -0.62 | 0.89 |
2. Total PUB 1962-02 | -0.81 | 0.22 | 0.06 | 0.31 | -0.34 | 0.89 |
3. Total PVT+Total PUB 1962-02 | -0.98 | 0.41 | -0.13 | 0.48** | -0.59 | 0.89 |
for the 1965-02 period. However, in the spillover case in 3. and 4. both 'all grant stocks' for PVT in 3. combined with agriculture PUB stocks, and the combination of national stocks for both PVT and PUB in 4., show significant elasticities for all variables. The size of the elasticities reflects the percentage increase in the TFP measure corresponding to a 1 percent change in the total R & D stocks as the case may be. In 3. the return on total private stocks is about $2.5 per dollar of stocks. The return on public stocks is negative $0.96. However the importance of these experiments relates more to defining a suitable investment proxy than the estimated rate of return.
Table 6: Experiments with the Agriculture Sector TFP (5) | ||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
'Grants' | ||||||
Description | Constant | PVT | PUB | AUST | EDU | R2 |
1. 'Grants' PVT, new shares 1965-98 | -1.78 | 0.43 | -0.14 | 0.47 | -0.38 | 0.83 |
2. 'Grants' PVT, new shares 1965-02 | -1.09 | 0.17 | 0.17 | 0.58 | -0.74* | 0.86 |
3. Total PVT 'Grants' 1965-02 |
-6.03 | 1.50** | -1.02** | 0.85** | -0.69* | 0.89 |
4. Total PVT +Total PUB 1965-02 |
-4.60 | 1.41* | -0.95* | 0.86** | -0.74* | 0.88 |
The search for a better definition of private investment in R & D has had mixed results. The specification based on research associations failed to indicate a significant relationship with agricultural TFP but showed a just significant relationship for the market economy for the period 1962-2002 (option 5, Table 1).
However, the specification based on government grants to the private sector shows more promise. In the market economy (option 7, Table 1), all four independent variables show significant association with market economy TFP. In the agricultural sector (options 1 and 2, Table 6), substituting the grants PVT variable does not relate to agricultural TFP. However, in the spillover hypothesis, the national total for stocks based on grants (options 3 and 4, Table 6), has a definite relationship to changes in agricultural TFP. This suggests that it would be worthwhile to repeat the Johnson (1999) analysis and the Johnson et al analysis (2006) based on combined cross section and time series data.
In summary, the earlier MoRST idea that industries can nominate the research expenditure that applies to them is a weak one. As it happens, MoRST has dropped the idea of 'output areas' from more recent surveys and publications. The presence of any spillovers at all in the science market negates the idea of specific output areas. Instead, science knowledge should be regarded as a generally available pool of knowledge and the science discovery process in industry should be concerned with determining what is useful in a particular application out of all that is available.
Further I now question whether the Griliches (1979) notion that science expenditure can be converted to a stock of knowledge like a stock of capital assets is a workable proposition. A stock depends on the perpetual inventory model and needs a specified rate of real depreciation. Is the accumulation of science knowledge like this? Can we find some other way of identifying the influence of what is undoubtedly a large stream of social expenditure?
Griliches Z. (1979), Issues in Assessing the Contribution of R & D to Productivity Growth, Bell Journal of Economics 10(1), 92-116.
Hall J. and Scobie G. (2006) The Role of Research and Development in Productivity Growth: The Case of Agriculture in New Zealand: 1927 to 2001, New Zealand Treasury Working Paper 06/1.
Johnson R W M (1999), The Rate of Return on NZ Research and Development, NZ Association of Economists, Rotorua
Johnson R W M (2000a), Methodologies for Measuring the Accumulated Knowledge Base in Research and Development, NZ Association of Economists, Wellington.
Johnson R W M (2000b), The Rate of Return to New Zealand Research and Development Investments, MAF Policy Technical Paper No 12.
Johnson R W M (2000c), Crowding Out and Resulting Trends in Research Fund Allocation in New Zealand 1991-2000, NZ Economic Papers 34(1), pp129-147.
Johnson R W M, Razzak W A & Stillman S (2006), Has NZ benefited from its investment in research and development?, Applied Economics (forthcoming).
MoRST (1999), New Zealand Research and Development Statistics 1997/98, Publication No 17, Wellington.
Philpott B P (1994), Data base of Nominal and Real Output, Labour, and Capital Employed by SNA Industry group 1960-1990, RPEP Paper 265, Victoria University.
Philpott B P (1995), Real Net Capital Stock by SNA Production Groups New Zealand 1950-1991 RPEP Paper 270.
Scobie G. and Eveleens W. (1986), Agricultural Research: What's it Worth?, Ministry of Agriculture, Hamilton.
Table A1 : Derivation of 1999 Estimates of Private Investment in Research and Development, 1962-90 | |||
---|---|---|---|
Fiscal Year Ending | GOVT/gdp actual % | PTE/gdp est % | Investment est $m |
1962 | 0.0030 | 0.0015 | 4.31 |
1963 | 0.0029 | 0.0014 | 4.36 |
1964 | 0.0029 | 0.0015 | 5.09 |
1965 | 0.0033 | 0.0016 | 5.95 |
1966 | 0.0034 | 0.0017 | 6.82 |
1967 | 0.0038 | 0.0019 | 7.96 |
1968 | 0.0041 | 0.0020 | 8.75 |
1969 | 0.0042 | 0.0021 | 9.75 |
1970 | 0.0042 | 0.0021 | 10.78 |
1971 | 0.0044 | 0.0022 | 12.80 |
1972 | 0.0045 | 0.0023 | 15.82 |
1973 | 0.0047 | 0.0024 | 18.96 |
1974 | 0.0048 | 0.0024 | 22.05 |
1975 | 0.0053 | 0.0027 | 27.35 |
1976 | 0.0054 | 0.0027 | 31.71 |
1977 | 0.0048 | 0.0024 | 34.08 |
1978 | 0.0052 | 0.0026 | 40.40 |
1979 | 0.0060 | 0.0030 | 50.90 |
1980 | 0.0059 | 0.0030 | 59.37 |
1981 | 0.0062 | 0.0031 | 71.58 |
1982 | 0.0064 | 0.0033 | 92.36 |
1983 | 0.0064 | 0.0033 | 104.08 |
1984 | 0.0059 | 0.0033 | 115.13 |
1985 | 0.0055 | 0.0033 | 130.45 |
1986 | 0.0057 | 0.0032 | 145.37 |
1987 | n.a. | 0.0031 | 176.32 |
1988 | n.a. | 0.0031 | 191.76 |
1989 | n.a. | 0.0030 | 199.20 |
1990 | 0.0039 | 0.0028 | 217.20 |
Table A2: Expenditure On Research and Development By Providers In New Zealand | |||||||
---|---|---|---|---|---|---|---|
Nominal Expenditure | Real Expenditure | ||||||
Fiscal Year Ending | Private Sector | Govt. Sector | Univ. Sector | Deflator $82-83 | Private | Public | Total |
1962 | 4.3 | 7.6 | 2.6 | 168 | 25.6 | 60.7 | 86.3 |
1963 | 4.4 | 8.1 | 2.8 | 177 | 24.9 | 61.6 | 86.4 |
1964 | 5.1 | 8.7 | 3.1 | 182 | 28.0 | 64.8 | 92.9 |
1965 | 5.9 | 10.5 | 3.4 | 185 | 31.9 | 75.1 | 107.0 |
1966 | 6.8 | 12.1 | 4.1 | 191 | 35.6 | 84.8 | 120.4 |
1967 | 7.9 | 14.2 | 4.8 | 192 | 41.1 | 99.0 | 140.1 |
1968 | 8.7 | 15.7 | 5.8 | 202 | 43.1 | 106.4 | 149.5 |
1969 | 9.7 | 17.1 | 6.7 | 210 | 46.2 | 113.3 | 159.5 |
1970 | 10.8 | 19.9 | 7.7 | 221 | 48.9 | 124.9 | 173.8 |
1971 | 12.8 | 23.1 | 9.8 | 242 | 52.9 | 136.0 | 188.8 |
1972 | 15.8 | 28.1 | 13.1 | 278 | 56.8 | 148.2 | 205.0 |
1973 | 19.1 | 33.9 | 17.8 | 307 | 62.2 | 168.4 | 230.6 |
1974 | 22.1 | 39.7 | 24.1 | 333 | 66.4 | 191.6 | 258.0 |
1975 | 27.4 | 49.4 | 27.6 | 353 | 77.6 | 218.1 | 295.8 |
1976 | 31.7 | 58.1 | 31.8 | 402 | 78.9 | 223.6 | 302.5 |
1977 | 34.1 | 62.7 | 30.2 | 486 | 70.2 | 191.2 | 261.3 |
1978 | 40.4 | 74.1 | 34.1 | 523 | 77.2 | 206.9 | 284.1 |
1979 | 50.9 | 92.4 | 41.2 | 591 | 86.1 | 226.1 | 312.2 |
1980 | 59.4 | 103.8 | 38.1 | 673 | 88.3 | 210.8 | 299.1 |
1981 | 71.6 | 128.3 | 47.1 | 774 | 92.5 | 226.6 | 319.1 |
1982 | 92.4 | 163.5 | 55.5 | 894 | 103.4 | 245.0 | 348.3 |
1983 | 104.1 | 184.5 | 59.9 | 1000 | 104.1 | 244.4 | 348.5 |
1984 | 115.1 | 187.9 | 61.6 | 1080 | 106.6 | 231.0 | 337.6 |
1985 | 130.4 | 197.1 | 64.1 | 1164 | 112.0 | 224.4 | 336.4 |
1986 | 145.4 | 230.7 | 84.7 | 1329 | 109.4 | 237.3 | 346.7 |
1987 | 176.3 | 226.1 | 105.2 | 1572 | 112.2 | 210.8 | 322.9 |
1988 | 191.7 | 249.4 | 113.9 | 1763 | 108.7 | 206.1 | 314.8 |
1989 | 199.2 | 259.1 | 137.9 | 1910 | 104.3 | 207.9 | 312.1 |
1990 | 217.2 | 290.2 | 139.2 | 2017 | 107.7 | 212.9 | 320.6 |
1991 | 217.1 | 318.2 | 166.3 | 2069 | 104.9 | 234.2 | 339.1 |
1992 | 222.7 | 317.2 | 177.1 | 2096 | 106.3 | 235.8 | 342.1 |
1993 | 229.2 | 312.4 | 232.4 | 2136 | 107.3 | 255.1 | 362.4 |
1994 | 263.3 | 343.4 | 233.5 | 2178 | 120.9 | 264.9 | 385.8 |
1995 | 257.1 | 358.1 | 254.1 | 2214 | 116.1 | 276.5 | 392.6 |
1996 | 252.5 | 375.6 | 273.5 | 2258 | 111.8 | 287.5 | 399.3 |
1997 | 282.0 | 389.0 | 340.0 | 2287 | 123.3 | 318.7 | 442.0 |
1998 | 312.5 | 391.3 | 403.6 | 2335 | 133.8 | 340.4 | 474.2 |
1999 | 316.0 | 387.0 | 372.0 | 2353 | 134.3 | 322.6 | 456.9 |
2000 | 324.1 | 393.1 | 374.1 | 2354 | 137.6 | 325.9 | 463.5 |
2001 | 367.0 | 421.0 | 402.0 | 2436 | 150.6 | 337.8 | 488.4 |
2002 | 419.4 | 453.1 | 435.8 | 2529 | 165.8 | 351.5 | 517.3 |
2003 | 470.7 | 472.1 | 454.8 | 2543 | 185.1 | 364.5 | 549.6 |
2004 | 522.0 | 491.1 | 454.8 | 2637 | 198.0 | 358.7 | 556.7 |
Table A3: Total Market Research and Development Stock at 5% Depreciation $1983 | |||
---|---|---|---|
Fiscal Year | Private | Public | Total1 |
1961-622 | 170.6 | 404.7 | 575.3 |
1963 | 186.9 | 446.0 | 633.0 |
1964 | 205.6 | 488.6 | 694.2 |
1965 | 227.2 | 539.3 | 766.5 |
1966 | 251.5 | 597.1 | 848.6 |
1967 | 280.0 | 666.2 | 946.3 |
1968 | 309.1 | 739.4 | 1048.5 |
1969 | 339.8 | 815.7 | 1155.6 |
1970 | 371.7 | 899.8 | 1271.5 |
1971 | 406.0 | 990.8 | 1396.8 |
1972 | 442.6 | 1089.5 | 1532.0 |
1973 | 482.6 | 1203.4 | 1686.0 |
1974 | 524.9 | 1334.8 | 1859.7 |
1975 | 576.2 | 1486.2 | 2062.4 |
1976 | 626.3 | 1635.5 | 2261.8 |
1977 | 665.1 | 1744.9 | 2410.0 |
1978 | 709.1 | 1864.5 | 2573.7 |
1979 | 759.8 | 1997.4 | 2757.2 |
1980 | 810.1 | 2108.3 | 2918.4 |
1981 | 862.1 | 2229.5 | 3091.6 |
1982 | 922.3 | 2363.0 | 3285.4 |
1983 | 980.3 | 2489.3 | 3469.6 |
1984 | 1037.9 | 2595.8 | 3633.7 |
1985 | 1098.0 | 2690.4 | 3788.4 |
1986 | 1152.5 | 2793.2 | 3945.7 |
1987 | 1207.0 | 2864.3 | 4071.4 |
1988 | 1255.4 | 2927.2 | 4182.6 |
1989 | 1296.9 | 2988.7 | 4285.6 |
1990 | 1339.8 | 3052.1 | 4391.9 |
1991 | 1377.7 | 3133.7 | 4511.4 |
1992 | 1415.1 | 3212.8 | 4627.9 |
1993 | 1451.6 | 3307.3 | 4758.9 |
1994 | 1499.9 | 3406.8 | 4906.7 |
1995 | 1541.1 | 3512.9 | 5054.0 |
1996 | 1575.8 | 3624.8 | 5200.6 |
1997 | 1620.3 | 3762.3 | 5382.6 |
1998 | 1673.1 | 3914.5 | 5587.6 |
1999 | 1723.7 | 4041.4 | 5765.1 |
2000 | 1775.2 | 4165.2 | 5940.4 |
2001 | 1837.0 | 4294.8 | 6131.8 |
2002 | 1910.9 | 4431.5 | 6342.4 |
2003 | 2006.4 | 4571.8 | 6578.2 |
2004 | 2103.9 | 4701.9 | 6805.8 |
Notes: | |||
1. Starting stock = $86.3/(0.1 + 0.05) | |||
Starting stock = $575.3m (in $1982-83) | |||
2. End of year stock | |||
0.1 is the growth rate of Research and Development expenditure 1962-72 | |||
0.05 is the annual depreciation rate |
Table A4: Revised Private Investment and Stock $m | |||
---|---|---|---|
Research Associations. | |||
Fiscal Year | Current Inv | Real Inv | Stock |
1961-62 | 1.8 | 11.0 | 73.4 |
1963 | 2.4 | 13.5 | 83.2 |
1964 | 2.5 | 14.0 | 93.0 |
1965 | 3.8 | 20.4 | 108.7 |
1966 | 4.4 | 22.9 | 126.2 |
1967 | 6.2 | 32.3 | 152.2 |
1968 | 6.9 | 34.2 | 178.7 |
1969 | 8.2 | 39.0 | 208.7 |
1970 | 9.6 | 43.3 | 241.6 |
1971 | 10.3 | 42.8 | 272.3 |
1972 | 12.4 | 44.5 | 303.2 |
1973 | 12.0 | 39.1 | 327.1 |
1974 | 13.7 | 41.2 | 352.0 |
1975 | 17.0 | 48.0 | 382.4 |
1976 | 18.7 | 46.5 | 409.8 |
1977 | 20.3 | 41.9 | 431.2 |
1978 | 24.7 | 47.2 | 456.8 |
1979 | 22.5 | 38.1 | 472.1 |
1980 | 32.4 | 48.1 | 496.6 |
1981 | 39.0 | 50.4 | 522.2 |
1982 | 50.0 | 55.9 | 552.0 |
1983 | 59.1 | 59.1 | 583.5 |
1984 | 63.9 | 59.1 | 613.5 |
1985 | 68.9 | 59.2 | 642.1 |
1986 | 83.5 | 62.8 | 672.8 |
1987 | 113.0 | 71.9 | 711.0 |
1988 | 192.0 | 108.9 | 784.4 |
1989 | 205.3 | 107.5 | 852.6 |
1990 | 217.2 | 107.7 | 917.7 |
1991 | 217.1 | 104.9 | 976.7 |
1992 | 222.7 | 106.3 | 1034.1 |
1993 | 229.2 | 107.3 | 1089.7 |
1994 | 263.3 | 120.9 | 1156.1 |
1995 | 257.1 | 116.1 | 1214.5 |
1996 | 252.5 | 111.8 | 1265.6 |
1997 | 282.0 | 123.3 | 1325.6 |
1998 | 312.5 | 133.8 | 1393.1 |
1999 | 316.0 | 134.3 | 1457.7 |
2000 | 324.1 | 137.6 | 1522.5 |
2001 | 367.0 | 150.6 | 1596.9 |
2002 | 419.4 | 165.8 | 1682.9 |
2003 | 470.7 | 191.0 | 1789.7 |
2004 | 522.0 | 197.9 | 1898.2 |
Table A5: Sector Shares for 1989-90 | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Private Shares | Public Shares | |||
1999 shares | Revised | 1999 shares | Revised | |
Agriculture | 0.086 | 0.0543 | 0.374 | 0.2967 |
Fishing | 0.005 | 0.0055 | 0.066 | 0.0488 |
Forestry | 0.009 | 0.0096 | 0.051 | 0.0387 |
Pr Processing | 0.340 | 0.3253 | 0.062 | 0.0521 |
Manufacturing | 0.291 | 0.3258 | 0.092 | 0.0892 |
Building | 0.018 | 0.0239 | 0.002 | 0.0078 |
Energy | 0.034 | 0.0277 | 0.005 | 0.0102 |
Transport | 0.024 | 0.0217 | 0.009 | 0.0076 |
Services | 0.193 | 0.2060 | 0.339 | 0.4523 |
Note: Private shares do not vary between 1962 and 1990 whereas public shares do vary. Revised shares take into account university grants by output areas. Public shares available on request. | ||||
Source: MoRST (various) |
Table A6: Structure of 'Grants' Variable | ||||
---|---|---|---|---|
Fiscal Years | Grants $th/nom | Raised Total $th/nom | Real Exp $m | Real stock $m @ 0.05% |
64-5 | 1412 | 10639.42 | 57.51 | 383.40 |
65-6 | 1737 | 13088.30 | 68.53 | 432.76 |
66-7 | 1910 | 14391.85 | 74.96 | 486.08 |
67-8 | 2136 | 16094.76 | 79.68 | 541.45 |
68-9 | 2429 | 18302.52 | 87.15 | 601.53 |
69-0 | 2723 | 20517.81 | 92.84 | 664.30 |
70-1 | 2395 | 18046.33 | 74.57 | 705.65 |
71-2 | 2989 | 22522.12 | 81.01 | 751.39 |
72-3 | 3628 | 27336.98 | 89.05 | 802.86 |
73-4 | 4124 | 31074.34 | 93.32 | 856.04 |
74-5 | 4613 | 34758.96 | 98.47 | 911.70 |
75-6 | 5426 | 40884.91 | 101.70 | 967.82 |
76-7 | 5682 | 42813.87 | 88.09 | 1007.52 |
77-8 | 6179 | 46558.77 | 89.02 | 1046.17 |
78-9 | 9369 | 70595.42 | 119.45 | 1113.31 |
79-0 | 12404 | 93464.14 | 138.88 | 1196.52 |
80-1 | 14275 | 107562.13 | 138.97 | 1275.67 |
81-2 | 16307 | 122873.25 | 137.44 | 1349.32 |
82-3 | 18007 | 135682.75 | 135.68 | 1417.54 |
83-4 | 16237 | 122345.80 | 113.28 | 1459.95 |
84-5 | 17248 | 129963.68 | 111.65 | 1498.60 |
85-6 | 25849 | 194772.22 | 146.56 | 1570.23 |
86-7 | 27806 | 209518.21 | 133.28 | 1625.00 |
87-8 | 28013 | 211077.96 | 119.73 | 1663.47 |
88-9 | 28455 | 214408.43 | 112.26 | 1692.56 |
89-0 | 28800 | 217008.00 | 107.68 | 1715.61 |
90-1 | 104.88 | 1734.71 | ||
91-2 | 106.25 | 1754.23 | ||
92-3 | 107.30 | 1773.82 | ||
93-4 | 120.89 | 1806.02 | ||
94-5 | 116.08 | 1831.80 | ||
95-6 | 111.82 | 1852.03 | ||
96-7 | 123.30 | 1882.73 | ||
97-8 | 133.80 | 1922.40 | ||
98-9 | 134.30 | 1960.58 | ||
99-0 | 137.60 | 2000.15 | ||
00-1 | 150.60 | 2050.74 | ||
01-2 | 165.80 | 2114.00 | ||
02-3 | 191.00 | 2199.30 | ||
03-4 | 197.90 | 2287.24 | ||
Notes: Total investment is estimated in proportion to the grants made so as to be equivalent to the MoRST data for 1989-90. Up to 1988-89 this gives a revised estimate of real private expenditure on Research and Development. Thereafter, the MoRST investment is shown. Since the starting stock is amortised at the expenditure level of 1964-65, the whole stock series is revised. | ||||
Source: NZ YearBooks |
[1] Consultant, 59 Allington Road, Wellington; (johnson r 1 at paradise dot net dot nz). Paper prepared for 2006 meeting of NZ Association of Economists.
[2] Wool Research Organisation of New Zealand, Dairy Research Institute (now Fonterra), and Leather and Shoe Research Association.
[3] DRI expenditure increased by 83% in 1987-88, Leather expenditure increased by 14% in 1985-86, MIRINZ expenditure increased by 55% in 1989-90, and WRONZ expenditure increased by 55% in 1987-88. At the time of writing I am not sure what is going on here.